Pexels allan carvalho 264847051 15312102

The Invisible Hand: Revisiting a Misunderstood Metaphor

Adam Smith, hailed as the father of modern economics, is often inseparable from the idea of the “invisible hand”. The invisible hand is widely understood as a metaphor illustrating how individual actions may unintentionally benefit society as a whole. However, to fully grasp this concept, we must take a step back from modern interpretations and revisit the contexts in which Adam Smith used the term.

Adam Smith, hailed as the father of modern economics, is often inseparable from the idea of the “invisible hand” – a metaphor widely seen as a cornerstone of his philosophy. This metaphor has been elevated to an almost legendary status, seen as the foundation of laissez-faire economics and sometimes even as a guiding principle in policy-making.

Yet, surprisingly, this phrase appears only three times in his writings, and each instance reflects a unique context and interpretation. Why, then, has it come to define his legacy? And more importantly, what does it truly signify?

In this article, I will delve into how the invisible hand extends beyond economics, offering deeper insights into human motivation that are still relevant in today’s world. By revisiting Smith’s original works, I will challenge the common misinterpretations of this metaphor and present a refreshed understanding of its meaning, helping to uncover a better understanding of what truly drives human actions and collective well-being.[1]


What Is the Invisible Hand?

At its core, the invisible hand is widely understood as a metaphor illustrating how individual actions – often driven by self-interest – unintentionally benefit society as a whole. Often, it is interpreted as a justification for free markets, where self-interest drives efficiency and prosperity without the need for heavy-handed regulation [2].

However, to fully grasp this concept, we must take a step back from modern interpretations and revisit the contexts in which Adam Smith used the term. Across his original writings, the invisible hand emerges three times, each instance revealing a distinct meaning:

  1. In "The History of Astronomy" (1755)[3]: Smith refers to the "invisible
    hand of Jupiter" to describe interpretations of natural phenomena that
    were, at the time, beyond scientific explanation. This reflects the idea
    of an unseen cosmic order attributed to specific circumstances.
  2. In "The Theory of Moral Sentiments" (1759)[4]: Here, Smith discusses how
    wealthy individuals, driven by self-interest, indirectly support the
    poor through their consumption and investment. This unintended
    contribution to providing the necessities of life for the poor is
    presented as an almost divine phenomenon, ultimately advancing society's
    interests.
  3. In "The Wealth of Nations" (1776)[5]: In this most famous usage of
    the concept, Smith describes a merchant who, seeking profit in
    domestic rather than foreign industry, is “led by an invisible hand
    to promote an end which was no part of his intention.” This end,
    once again, is the promotion of local society's interests.

Yet, a closer examination of all three occurrences reveals significant differences in their contexts and implications. This is particularly evident when considering the first instance, which addresses inexplicable natural phenomena and appears largely unrelated to the subsequent two mentions. Notably, this initial reference to the metaphor was never published by Smith himself; it emerged almost half a century later, posthumously, despite his explicit instructions to destroy most of his unpublished works or notes[6].

Let us assume then—as has often been done in economics[7]—that this is reason enough to disregard this first occurrence. Confining oneself to reading only the two more relevant occurrences one could indeed discern a common thread: individual actions seem to lead to unintended consequences that often align with society’s interests. Yet, even then, a fundamental question arises: what motivates these actions?


Understanding Human Motivation: Beyond Selfishness

The popular interpretation of the invisible hand often emphasizes selfishness as the sole driver of human actions and behavior. This is most likely – at least in part – attributable to Smith’s famous statement in The Wealth of Nations (1776)[8]:

“It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest. We address ourselves, not to their humanity but to their self-love, and never talk to them of our own necessities but of their advantages.”

At first glance, this suggests that self-interest – and therefore self-love – is the central driver behind human actions. However, one must not be too hasty in reducing self-love to blatant selfishness. As a matter of fact, returning to Smith’s earlier work, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759) reveals a far more nuanced view. In this work, the author explores how “self-love” influences human actions and even demarcates different forms of it.

A recent interpretation by scholar Michele Bee (2021)[9] has helped clarify these human motivations, by distinguishing the three types of self-love in Smith’s earlier work:

  1. The Love of Vanity (or vanity): A desire to gain the esteem of others, prompting us to conform to social norms.
  2. The Love of Virtue (or love of praiseworthiness): An aspiration to act ethically and morally.
  3. The Love of True Glory (or love of deserved praise): A combination of the first two, where individuals seek recognition for efforts that align with social values.

This third type of self-love is particularly revealing. It demonstrates that according to Smith, humans are not solely driven by selfish gains[10] but also by a need for respect and approval. The need for social respect and ethical alignment is a core motivation and one that often encourages socially beneficial behaviors, such as the ones that Smith alludes to with his invisible hand metaphor.


Rethinking the Invisible Hand

Reinterpreting the invisible hand through this lens complicates its traditional meaning. It is about more than just selfishness creating societal benefits. Instead, it reflects a rather delicate interplay between personal interests and social expectations.

Consider an entrepreneur. While certainly motivated by profit, they may also seek recognition for their success and contributions. This dual motivation may lead them to innovate, create jobs, and strengthen social cohesion. In fulfilling their self-interest, they simultaneously fulfill their self-love—enhancing both their personal satisfaction and societal well-being.

Why This Matters Today

Understanding the original essence of the invisible hand metaphor has quite significant implications for how we think about markets and society today – some aspects of which are built on the assumption that selfishness or greed alone can lead to positive outcomes for society.

If factors like the desire for approval, virtue, and ethical recognition are as central as profit, then policies that encourage collaboration, community-building, and sustainability may align more naturally with human behavior. This interpretation is at odds with what is now called “trickle down economics” as well as some branches of free-market ideology, suggesting that mechanisms based solely on competition and profit maximization may be more often than not insufficient to achieve the common good.

Conclusion

The invisible hand isn’t simply an economic metaphor; it’s a profound idea about the forces linking individual actions to collective well-being. By looking beyond simple self-interest, Adam Smith’s work – and modern interpretations like Michele Bee’s – offer a richer, more human vision of society. In this case, balancing profit with respect, virtue, and social norms is perhaps not only possible but also essential for the creation of beneficial social outcomes.


References

[1]

A primary source of inspiration for this article came from work and discussions with Professor Roberto Baranzini (Université de Lausanne), whose expertise in Adam Smith’s philosophy offered valuable guidance for this reinterpretation.

[2]

Wexler, M. (2011). Invisible hands: Intelligent design and free markets. Journal of Ideology, 33, 1–24.

[3]

Smith, A. (1755). History of Astronomy, reprinted in W.P.D Wightman and J.C. Bryce (eds.). 1981. Adam Smith Essays on Philosophical Subjects. Oxford: Clarendon Press, p. 49.

[4]

Smith, A. (1976). The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Vol. II in: The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, 7 vol., Oxford: University Press, p. 184.

[5]

Smith, A. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Vol. II (1st ed.). London: W. Strahan & T. Cadell. pp. 32–33.

[6]

Buchan, J. (2006). The Authentic Adam Smith: His Life and Ideas. New York: W.W. Norton & Company. p. 88.

[7]

Aspromourgos, T. (2020). Invisible Hand. In: Vernengo, M., Caldentey, E.P., Rosser Jr, B.J. (eds.) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. pp.1-10. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_3108-1

[8]

Smith, A. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Vol. II (1st ed.). London: W. Strahan & T. Cadell. pp. 42–43.

[9]

Bee, M. (2021). The pleasure of exchange: Adam Smith’s third kind of self-love. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 43(1), 1-20.

[10]

Blanc, E. (2021). De l’intérêt égoïste à l’empathie. Journal of Interdisciplinary History of Ideas, 10(19), 4.

Autor*innen

Autor*in

Lorjen Doehler is an Economics and Social Sciences major at the University of Neuchâtel in Switzerland, during which time he studied abroad at the University of Technology Sydney and the London School of Economics. Passionate about leveraging social sciences to address contemporary challenges, Lorjen focuses on interdisciplinary research with the goal of informing policy, particularly in the areas of welfare and sustainability. As an elected local councilor, he applies his academic insights to shaping impactful policies for his community.Outside of academics, Lorjen enjoys learning new languages and mentoring fellow students. He is also a proud member of the Swiss Study Foundation.

Die Beiträge auf dem Reatch-Blog geben die persönliche Meinung der Autor*innen wieder und entsprechen nicht zwingend derjenigen von Reatch oder seiner Mitglieder.

Zum Kommentieren mehr als 20 Zeichen im Text markieren und Sprechblase anklicken.

Wir freuen uns über nützliche Anmerkungen. Die Kommentare werden moderiert.